Dictionary Definition
unemployed adj : not engaged in a gainful
occupation; "unemployed workers marched on the capital" [ant:
employed]
User Contributed Dictionary
English
Pronunciation
- Rhymes: -ɔɪd
Adjective
- Having no job (despite being able and willing to work).
Synonyms
- jobless
- out of work (used only after the noun)
Translations
having no job
- Czech: nezaměstnaný
- Dutch: werkloos, werkloze
- Finnish: työtön
- French: au chômage invariant
- German: arbeitslos
- Italian: disoccupato , disoccupata
- Kurdish:
- Northern Sami: bargguheapme, bargguheapmi
- Polish: bezrobotny , niezatrudniony
- Portuguese: desempregado
- Swedish: arbetslös
Related terms
Noun
- (the unemployed; plural) Unemployed people considered as a group.
Synonyms
Translations
the unemployed as a group
- Dutch: werklozen m, f, pl
- Finnish: työttömät
- French: les chômeurs m pl
- German: die Arbeitslosen m pl
- Italian: i disoccupati m pl
- Polish: bezrobotni p
- Portuguese: os desempregados m pl
Extensive Definition
Unemployment is the state in which a person is
without work, available
to work, and is currently seeking work. The unemployment rate is
used in economic
studies and economic indexes such as the United
States' Conference
Board's
Index of Leading Indicators. The rate is determined as the
percentage of those in the labor force
without jobs.
Types
According to economist Edmond Malinvaud, the type of unemployment that occurs depends on the situation at the goods market, rather than that they belong to opposing economic theories. If the market for goods is a buyers' market (i.e.: sales are restricted by demand), Keynesian unemployment may ensue while a limiting production capacity is more consistent with classical unemployment.A common typology of unemployment is the
following:
Frictional unemployment
Frictional unemployment occurs when a worker moves from one job to another. While he searches for a job he is experiencing frictional unemployment. This is a productive part of the economy, increasing both the worker's long term welfare and economic efficiencyClassical unemployment
Classical or real-wage unemployment occurs when real wages for a job are set above the market-clearing level. This is often ascribed to government intervention, as with the minimum wage, or labour unions. Some, such as Murray Rothbard, suggest that even social taboos can prevent wages from falling to the market clearing level.Structural unemployment
Structural unemployment is caused by a mismatch
between jobs offered by employers and potential workers. This may
pertain to geographical location, skills, and many other
factors.
If such a mismatch exists, frictional
unemployment is likely to be more significant as well.
Seasonal
unemployment occurs when an occupation is not in demand at
certain seasons.
Keynesian unemployment
Cyclical or Keynesian
unemployment, also known as demand deficient unemployment, occurs
when there is not enough aggregate demand for the labor. This is
caused by a business
cycle recession, and wages not falling to meet the equilibrium
rate.
Causes
There is considerable debate among economists as to the causes of unemployment. Keynesian economics emphasizes unemployment resulting from insufficient effective demand for goods and service in the economy (cyclical unemployment). Others point to structural problems, inefficiencies, inherent in labour markets (structural unemployment). Classical or neoclassical economics tends to reject these explanations, and focuses more on rigidities imposed on the labor market from the outside, such as minimum wage laws, taxes, and other regulations that may discourage the hiring of workers (classical unemployment). Yet others see unemployment as largely due to voluntary choices by the unemployed (frictional unemployment).Though there have been several definitions of
voluntary and involuntary unemployment in the economics literature,
a simple distinction is often applied. Voluntary unemployment is
attributed to the individual unemployed workers (and their
decisions), whereas involuntary unemployment exists because of the
socio-economic environment (including the market structure,
government intervention, and the level of aggregate demand) in
which individuals operate. In these terms, much or most of
frictional unemployment is voluntary, since it reflects individual
search behavior. On the other hand, cyclical unemployment,
structural unemployment, and classical unemployment, are largely
involuntary in nature. However, the existence of structural
unemployment may reflect choices made by the unemployed in the
past, while classical unemployment may result from the legislative
and economic choices made by labor unions and/or political
parties. So in practice, the distinction between voluntary and
involuntary unemployment is hard to draw. The clearest cases of
involuntary unemployment are those where there are fewer job
vacancies than unemployed workers even when wages are allowed to
adjust, so that even if all vacancies were to be filled, there
would be unemployed workers. This is the case of cyclical
unemployment, for which macroeconomic forces lead to microeconomic
unemployment. See also: unemployment
types
Some argue one of the main causes of unemployment
in a free market economy is that the
law of supply and demand is not really applied to the price to
be paid for employing people. In situations of falling demand for
products and services the wages of all employees, from president to
errand boy, are not automatically reduced by the required
percentage to make the business viable. Others say that it is the
market that determines the wages based on the desirability of the
job. The more people qualified and interested in the job, the lower
the wages for that job become. Based on this view, the
profitability of the company is not a factor in determining whether
or not the work is profitable to the employee. People are laid off,
because pay reductions would reduce the number of people willing to
work a job. With fewer people interested in a particular job, the
employees bargaining power would actually rise to stabilize the
situation, but their employer would be unable to fulfill their wage
expectations. In the classical framework, such unemployment is due
to the existing legal framework, along with interferences with the
market by non-market institutions such as labor unions and
government. Others say many of the problems with market adjustment
arise from the market itself (Keynes), or from the nature of
capitalism (Marx).
In developing countries unemployment is often
caused by burdensome government regulation. The World Bank's
Doing Business project shows how excessive labor regulation
increases unemployment among women and youths in Africa, the Middle
East and Latin America.
Open unemployment is generally associated with
capitalist economies.
In this view, unemployment is not an aberration of capitalism,
indicating any sort of systemic malfunction. Rather, unemployment
is a necessary structural feature of capitalism, intended to
discipline the workforce. If unemployment is too low, workers make
wage demands that either cuts into profits to an extent that
jeopardize future investment, or are passed on to consumers, thus
generating inflationary instability. David
Schweickart suggests, "Capitalism cannot be a full-employment
economy, except in the very short term. For unemployment is the
"invisible
hand" -- carrying a stick -- that keeps the workforce in
line.".
Classical economists dispute this, arguing that
when there is too high a supply of labour, providing unions and
Government have no prevented wage changes, the wage rate should
fall, returning the economy to it's long run efficient position at
full employment.
Unemployment increases the more the government
intervenes into the economy to try to improve the rights of those
with jobs. For example, minimum wages raise the cost of labour to
above the market equilibrium, resulting in people who wish to work
at the going rate but cannot as the wages are higher than their
worth to business; unemployment. Laws restricting layoffs make
businesses less likely to hire in the first place leaving many
young people unemployed and unable to find work.
The results of both actions lead to less
productivity and are claimed to incur a higher cost on society as a
whole. The results lead to not just higher unemployment but may
increase poverty. This is why the less market oriented countries of
Europe often sustain substantially high unemployment rates in
comparison to the United States; that is, government induced
employment through policies designed to protect the worker. The
welfare state then responds with various benefits that are paid for
by the middle and upper class which reduces their ability to
consume and reduces the incentive to work hard and innovate for all
sections of society, as the poor have income without working and
the rich see their reward for work reduced. Economists like
Ludwig
Von Mises, Milton
Friedman, Friedrich
Von Hayek not only believe that the welfare of society
decreases with this kind of intervention but that these economic
policies are not sustainable.
Okun's Law
Okun's law states that for every 2% GDP falls relative to potential GDP, unemployment rises 1%. When the economy operates at productive capacity, it will experience the Natural rate of unemployment.Solutions
At an individual level, the solution to
unemployment may be as simple as getting a job, or getting more
training.
Societies try a number of different measures to
get as many people as possible into work. However, attempts to
reduce the level of unemployment beyond the
Natural rate of unemployment generally fail, resulting only in
less output and more inflation.
Philips Curve
It used to be largely believed that unemployment could be solved using the Philips curve. This involves increasing inflation to reduce unemployment by fooling workers into accepting jobs at a lower rate than they would otherwise have done, due to the declining value of money. However, since the work of Milton Friedman, it is widely accepted that the Philips curve is vertical in the long run: you cannot achieve a lowering of the unemployment rate in the long run, and attempts to do so will only cause inflation.Demand side
Normal markets reach equilbrium, where supply
equals demand; everyone who wants to sell at the market price can.
Those who do not want to sell at this price do not; in the labour
market this is classical unemployment. Increases in the demand for
labour will move the economy along the supply curve, increasing
wages and employment. The demand for labour in an economy is
derived from the demand for goods and services. As such, if the
demand for goods and services in the economy increases, the demand
for labour will increase, increasing employment and wages.
Monetary policy and fiscal policy can both be
used to increase short-term growth in the economy, increasing the
demand for labour and decreasing unemployment.
Supply side
However, the labour market is not efficient: it
doesn't clear. Minimum wages and union activity keep wages from
falling, which means too many people want to sell their labour at
the going price but cannot. Supply-side
policies can solve this by making the labour market more flexible.
These include removing the minimum wage and reducing the power of
unions, which act as a labour cartel. Other supply side policies
include education to make workers more attractive to
employers.
Supply side reforms also increase long-term
growth. This increased supply of goods and services requires more
workers, increasing employment. Supply side policies, which include
cutting taxes on businesses and reducing regulation, 'create jobs
and reduce unemployment' according to the 2005 Budget report.
Tax-related
One structural solution to unemployment proposes a graduated retail tax, or "jobs levy", to firms where labor is more expensive than capital. This method will shift tax burden to capital intensive firms and away from labor intensive firms. In theory this will make firms shift operations to a "golden mean" between labor intensive and capital intensive production. The excess tax revenue from the jobs levy would finance labor intensive public projects. However, by raising the value of labour artificially above capital, this would disencourage capital investment, the source of economic growth. With less growth, long-run employment would fallCosts of unemployment
Individual
Unemployed individuals are unable to earn money to meet financial obligations. Failure to pay mortgage payments or to pay rent may lead to homelessness through foreclosure or eviction. Unemployment increases susceptibility to malnutrition, illness, mental stress, and loss of self-esteem, leading to depression.Dr. M. Harvey Brenner conducted a study in 1979
on the "Influence of the Social Environment on Psychology." Brenner
found that for every 10% increase in the number of unemployed there
is a 1.2% in total mortality, a 1.7% increase in cardiovascular
disease, 1.3% more cirrhosis cases, 1.7% more
suicides, 0.4% more arrests, and 0.8% more assaults reported to the
police. A more recent study by Christopher Ruhm on the effect of
recessions on health found that several measures of health actually
improve during recessions. As for the impact of an economic
downturn on crime, during the Great
Depression, when unemployment rates exceeded 20% in many
countries, the crime rate did not decrease. Because unemployment
insurance in the U.S. typically does not replace 50% of the income
one received on the job (and one cannot receive it forever), the
unemployed often end up tapping welfare
programs such as Food Stamps
or accumulating debt.
Higher government transfer payments in the form of welfare and food
stamps decrease spending on productive economic goods, decreasing
GDP.
Some hold that many of the low-income jobs are
not really a better option than unemployment with a welfare
state (with its unemployment
insurance benefits). But since it is difficult or impossible to
get unemployment insurance benefits without having worked in the
past, these jobs and unemployment are more complementary than they
are substitutes. (These jobs are often held short-term, either by
students or by those trying to gain experience; turnover in most
low-paying jobs is high, in excess of 30%/year.) Unemployment
insurance keeps an available supply of workers for the low-paying
jobs, while the employers' choice of management techniques (low
wages and benefits, few chances for advancement) is made with the
existence of unemployment insurance in mind. This combination
promotes the existence of one kind of unemployment,
frictional unemployment.
Another cost for the unemployed is that the
combination of unemployment, lack of financial resources, and
social responsibilities may push unemployed workers to take jobs
that do not fit their skills or allow them to use their talents.
Unemployment can cause underemployment.
The fear of job loss can spur psychological
anxiety.
Society
An economy with high unemployment is not using all of the resources, i.e. labour, available to it. Since it is operating below its production possibility frontier, it could have higher output if all the workforce were usefully employed. However, there is a tradeoff between economic efficiency and unemployment: if the frictionally unemployed accepted the first job they were offered, they would be likely to be operating at below their skill level, reducing the economy's efficiency.It is estimated that, during the Great
Depression, unemployment due to sticky wages
cost the US economy
about $4,000 billion. This is many times larger than losses due to
monopolies, cartels and tariffs.
During a long period of unemployment, workers can
lose their skills, causing a loss of human capital. Being
unemployed can also reduce the life expectancy of workers by about
7 years
High unemployment can encourage xenophobia and protectionism as workers
fear that foreigners are stealing their jobs. Efforts to preserve
existing jobs of domestic and native workers include legal barriers
against "outsiders" who want jobs, obstacles to immigration, and/or tariffs and similar trade
barriers against foreign competitors.
Finally, a rising unemployment rate concentrates
the oligopsony power
of employers by increasing competition amongst workers for scarce
employment opportunities..
Historical unemployment
This section is extremely suspect and may represent a minorty viewPreliterate communities treat their members as
parts of an extended family and thus do not allow unemployment. In
precapitalist societies such as European feudalism, the serfs were
never "unemployed" because they had direct access to the land, and
the needed tools, and could thus work to produce crops. Just as on
the American frontier during the nineteenth century, there were day
laborers and subsistence farmers on poor land, whose position in
society was somewhat analogous to the unemployed of today. But they
were not truly unemployed, since they could find work and support
themselves on the land.
Under both ancient and modern systems of
slave-labor, slave-owners never let their property be unemployed
for long. (If anything, they would sell the unneeded laborer.)
Planned
economies such as the old Soviet Union
or today's Cuba typically provide
occupation for everyone, using substantial overstaffing if
necessary. (This is called "hidden unemployment," which is
sometimes seen as a kind of underemployment,
definition 3.)
Workers' cooperatives—such as those producing plywood in the U.S. Pacific
Northwest—do not let their members become unemployed unless the
co-op itself goes bankrupt. Artificially increasing employment in
this way however means employing workers beyond their worth: the
workers are making a loss, and are from society's point of view not
usefully employed.
Measurement
Though many people care about the number of unemployed, economists typically focus on the unemployment rate. This corrects for the normal increase in the number of people employed due to increases in population and increases in the labor force relative to the population. The unemployment rate is expressed as a percentage, and is calculated as follows: Unemployment\ Rate=\frac*100%As defined by the
International Labour Organization, "unemployed workers" are
those who are currently not working but are willing and able to
work for pay, currently available to work, and have actively
searched for work.
Since not all unemployment may be "open" and
counted by government agencies, official statistics on unemployment
may not be accurate.
The
ILO describes 4 different methods to calculate the unemployment
rate:
- Labour Force Sample Surveys are the most preferred method of unemployment rate calculation since they give the most comprehensive results and enables calculation of unemployment by different group categories such as race and gender. This method is the most internationally comparable.
- Official Estimates are determined by a combination of information from one or more of the other three methods. The use of this method has been declining in favor of Labour Surveys.
- Social Insurance Statistics such as unemployment benefits, are computed base on the number of persons insured representing the total labour force and the number of persons who are insured that are collecting benefits. This method has been heavily criticized due to the expiration of benefits before the person finds work.
- Employment Office Statistics are the least effective being that they only include a monthly tally of unemployed persons who enter employment offices. This method also includes unemployed who are not unemployed per the ILO definition.
European Union (Eurostat)
Eurostat, the statistical office of the European Union, defines unemployed as those persons age 15 to 74 who are not working, have looked for work in the last four weeks, and ready to start work within two weeks, which conform to ILO standards. Both the actual count and rate of employment are reported. Statistical data is available by member state, EU12, EU15, EU25, EU27, EA11, and EA13. Eurostat also includes a long-term unemployment rate. This is defined as part of the unemployed who have been unemployed for an excess of 1 year.Three methods of data collection are used in the
European Union. The European Union Labour Force Survey (EU-LFS)
collects data on all member states each quarter. For monthly
calculations, national surveys or national registers from
employment offices are used in conjunction with quarterly EU-LFS
data. Monthly unemployment rates are interpolated from monthly data
from member states to provide "harmonized data."
At this time Germany's
unemployment data is collected separately from the (EU-LFS).
United States Bureau of Labor Statistics
There was an official measure of 7.6 million unemployed in the U.S. as of January 2008, a rate of 4.9%.References
External links
unemployed in Afrikaans: Werkloosheid
unemployed in Arabic: بطالة
unemployed in Bosnian: Nezaposlenost
unemployed in Bulgarian: Безработица
unemployed in Catalan: Atur
unemployed in Czech: Nezaměstnanost
unemployed in Danish: Arbejdsløshed
unemployed in German: Arbeitslosigkeit
unemployed in Estonian: Tööpuudus
unemployed in Modern Greek (1453-):
Ανεργία
unemployed in Spanish: Desempleo
unemployed in Esperanto: Senlaboreco
unemployed in Basque: Langabezia
unemployed in Persian: بیکاری
unemployed in French: Chômage
unemployed in Galician: Desemprego
unemployed in Korean: 실업
unemployed in Croatian: Nezaposlenost
unemployed in Indonesian: Pengangguran
unemployed in Italian: Disoccupazione
unemployed in Hebrew: אבטלה
unemployed in Latvian: Bezdarbs
unemployed in Lithuanian: Bedarbystė
unemployed in Hungarian: Munkanélküliség
unemployed in Mongolian: Ажилгүйдэл
unemployed in Dutch: Werkloosheid
unemployed in Japanese: 失業
unemployed in Norwegian: Arbeidsledighet
unemployed in Norwegian Nynorsk:
Arbeidsløyse
unemployed in Occitan (post 1500):
Caumatge
unemployed in Polish: Bezrobocie
unemployed in Portuguese: Desemprego
unemployed in Romanian: Şomaj
unemployed in Russian: Безработица
unemployed in Albanian: Papunësia
unemployed in Simple English: Unemployment
unemployed in Slovak: Nezamestnanosť
unemployed in Slovenian: Brezposelnost
unemployed in Serbian: Незапосленост
unemployed in Serbo-Croatian:
Nezaposlenost
unemployed in Finnish: Työttömyys
unemployed in Swedish: Arbetslöshet
unemployed in Vietnamese: Thất nghiệp
unemployed in Turkish: İşsizlik
unemployed in Ukrainian: Безробіття
unemployed in Walloon: Tchômaedje
unemployed in Yiddish: ארבעטסלאזיקײט
unemployed in Chinese: 失業
Synonyms, Antonyms and Related Words
at a standstill, at anchor, at leisure, at
liberty, at loose ends, available, beggar, bummer, cadger, coupon clippers,
dead-still, disengaged, drone, extra, fallow, fired, fixed, free, freeloader, fresh, held back, held in reserve,
held out, idle, idle rich,
immobile, immotive, in abeyance, in hand,
jobless, leisure, leisure class, leisured, let go, lounge
lizard, lumpen, lumpen
proletariat, mendicant, mint, moocher, motionless, moveless, new, nonworker, off, off duty, off work, original, otiose, out of commission, out of
employ, out of harness, out of work, panhandler, parasite, pristine, put aside, put by,
rentiers, reserve, riding at anchor,
saved, spare, spiv, sponger, static, stationary, statuelike, still, stock-still, stored, suspended, the unemployable,
the unemployed, to spare, unapplied, unbeaten, unconsumed, unemployable, unengaged, unexercised, unexpended, unhandled, unmoved, unmoving, unoccupied, unspent, untapped, untouched, untrodden, unused, unutilized, waived, workless