User Contributed Dictionary
Verb
exported- past of export
Extensive Definition
International trade is the exchange of capital,
goods and services across international boundaries or territories.
In most countries, it represents a significant share of GDP.
While international trade
has been present throughout much of history (see Silk Road,
Amber
Road), its economic, social, and political importance has been
on the rise in recent centuries. Industrialization,
advanced transportation, globalization, multinational
corporations, and outsourcing are all having a
major impact on the international trade system. Increasing
international trade is crucial to the continuance of globalization.
International trade is a major source of economic revenue for any
nation that is considered a world power. Without international
trade, nations would be limited to the goods and services produced
within their own borders.
International trade is in principle not different
from domestic
trade as the motivation and the behavior of parties involved in
a trade does not change fundamentally depending on whether trade is
across a border or not. The main difference is that international
trade is typically more costly than domestic trade. The reason is
that a border typically imposes additional costs such as tariffs,
time costs due to border delays and costs associated with country
differences such as language, the legal system or a different
culture.
Another difference between domestic and
international trade is that factors
of production such as capital and labor are typically more
mobile within a country than across countries. Thus international
trade is mostly restricted to trade in goods and services, and only
to a lesser extent to trade in capital, labor or other factors of
production. Then trade in good and services can serve as a
substitute for trade in factors of production. Instead of importing
the factor of production a country can import goods that make
intensive use of the factor of production and are thus embodying
the respective factor. An example is the import of labor-intensive
goods by the United States from China. Instead of importing Chinese
labor the United States is importing goods from China that were
produced with Chinese labor.
International trade is also a branch of economics, which, together
with international
finance, forms the larger branch of international
economics.
Models
Several different models have been proposed to predict patterns of trade and to analyze the effects of trade policies such as tariffs.Ricardian model
The Ricardian model focuses on comparative advantage and is perhaps the most important concept in international trade theory. In a Ricardian model, countries specialize in producing what they produce best. Unlike other models, the Ricardian framework predicts that countries will fully specialize instead of producing a broad array of goods. Also, the Ricardian model does not directly consider factor endowments, such as the relative amounts of labor and capital within a country.Heckscher-Ohlin model
The Heckscher-Ohlin model was produced as an alternative to the Ricardian model of basic comparative advantage. Despite its greater complexity it did not prove much more accurate in its predictions. However from a theoretical point of view it did provide an elegant solution by incorporating the neoclassical price mechanism into international trade theory.The theory argues that the pattern of
international trade is determined by differences in factor endowments.
It predicts that countries will export those goods
that make intensive use of locally abundant factors and will import
goods that make intensive use of factors that are locally scarce.
Empirical problems with the H-O model, known as the Leontief
paradox, were exposed in empirical tests by Wassily
Leontief who found that the United States tended to export
labor intensive goods despite having a capital abundance.
Specific factors model
In this model, labour mobility between industries is possible while capital is immobile between industries in the short-run. Thus, this model can be interpreted as a 'short run' version of the Heckscher-Ohlin model. The specific factors name refers to the given that in the short-run specific factors of production, such as physical capital, are not easily transferable between industries. The theory suggests that if there is an increase in the price of a good, the owners of the factor of production specific to that good will profit in real terms. Additionally, owners of opposing specific factors of production (i.e. labour and capital) are likely to have opposing agendas when lobbying for controls over immigration of labour. Conversely, both owners of capital and labour profit in real terms from an increase in the capital endowment. This model is ideal for particular industries. This model is ideal for understanding income distribution but awkward for discussing the pattern of trade!New Trade Theory
New Trade theory tries to explain several facts about trade, which the two main models above have difficulty with. These include the fact that most trade is between countries with similar factor endowment and productivity levels, and the large amount of multinational production (ie foreign direct investment) which exists. In one example of this framework, the economy exhibits monopolistic competition, and increasing returns to scale.Gravity model
The Gravity model of trade presents a more empirical analysis of trading patterns rather than the more theoretical models discussed above. The gravity model, in its basic form, predicts trade based on the distance between countries and the interaction of the countries' economic sizes. The model mimics the Newtonian law of gravity which also considers distance and physical size between two objects. The model has been proven to be empirically strong through econometric analysis. Other factors such as income level, diplomatic relationships between countries, and trade policies are also included in expanded versions of the model.Regulation of international trade
Traditionally trade was regulated through
bilateral treaties
between two nations. For centuries under the belief in Mercantilism
most nations had high tariffs and many restrictions on
international trade. In the 19th century, especially in Britain, a
belief in free trade
became paramount. This belief became the dominant thinking among
western nations since then despite the acknowledgement that
adoption of the policy coincided with the general decline of Great
Britain. In the years since the Second
World War, controversial multilateral treaties like
the GATT and
World
Trade Organization have attempted to create a globally
regulated trade structure. These trade agreements have often
resulted in protest and discontent with claims of unfair trade that
is not mutually beneficial.
Free trade is usually most strongly supported by
the most economically powerful nations, though they often engage in
selective protectionism for those
industries which are strategically important such as the protective
tariffs applied to
agriculture by the
United
States and Europe. The Netherlands and
the United
Kingdom were both strong advocates of free trade when they were
economically dominant, today the United
States, the United
Kingdom, Australia and
Japan are its
greatest proponents. However, many other countries (such as India,
China and Russia) are increasingly becoming advocates of free trade
as they become more economically powerful themselves. As tariff
levels fall there is also an increasing willingness to negotiate
non tariff measures, including foreign direct investment,
procurement and trade
facilitation. The latter looks at the transaction
cost associated with meeting trade and customs procedures.
Traditionally agricultural interests are usually
in favour of free trade while manufacturing sectors often support
protectionism. This has changed somewhat in recent years, however.
In fact, agricultural lobbies, particularly in the United States,
Europe and Japan, are chiefly responsible for particular rules in
the major international trade treaties which allow for more
protectionist measures in agriculture than for most other goods and
services.
During recessions there is often
strong domestic pressure to increase tariffs to protect domestic
industries. This occurred around the world during the Great
Depression. Many economists have attempted to portray tariffs
as the underlining reason behind the collapse in world trade that
many believe seriously deepened the depression.
The regulation of international trade is done
through the World Trade Organization at the global level, and
through several other regional arrangements such as MERCOSUR in South
America, NAFTA between the
United States, Canada and Mexico, and the European
Union between 27 independent states. The 2005 Buenos Aires
talks on the planned establishment of the Free Trade Area of the
Americas (FTAA) failed largely due to opposition from the
populations of Latin American nations. Similar agreements such as
the MAI
(Multilateral
Agreement on Investment) have also failed in recent
years.
Risks in international trade
The risks that exist in international trade can be divided into two major groupsEconomic risks
- Risk of insolvency of the buyer,
- Risk of protracted default - the failure of the buyer to pay the amount due within six months after the due date
- Risk of non-acceptance
- Surrendering economic sovereignty
- Risk of Exchange rate
Political risks
- Risk of cancellation or non-renewal of export or import licences
- War risks
- Risk of expropriation or confiscation of the importer's company
- Risk of the imposition of an import ban after the shipment of the goods
- Transfer risk - imposition of exchange controls by the importer's country or foreign currency shortages
- Surrendering political sovereignty
- Influence of political parties in importer's company
See also
- Absolute advantage
- American trade
- Balance of trade
- Borderless Selling
- Columbian Exchange
- Comparative advantage
- Customs union
- Ecological Economics
- Economics
- Export
- Free trade
- Free trade area
- Gravity model of trade
- Import (international trade)
- International trade law
- International Trade Awards
- List of countries by imports
- List of countries by exports
- List of international trade topics
- List of economists
- Market Segmentation Index
- Most favoured nation clause
- OPEC
- Political risk
- Protectionism
- Single Window System
- The Grand Exchange
- Trade bloc
- Trade facilitation
- Trade of Japan
- Trade of Galicia
Footnotes
External links
Data
exported in Arabic: تجارة خارجية
exported in Catalan: Comerç internacional
exported in German: Außenwirtschaft
exported in Estonian: Rahvusvaheline
kaubandus
exported in Spanish: Comercio
internacional
exported in Esperanto: Internacia komerco
exported in French: Commerce international
exported in Korean: 국제 무역
exported in Indonesian: Perdagangan
internasional
exported in Hebrew: סחר בינלאומי
exported in Lao: ການຄ້າສາກົນ
exported in Hungarian: Külkereskedelem
exported in Japanese: 貿易
exported in Norwegian: Internasjonal
handel
exported in Norwegian Nynorsk: Internasjonal
handel
exported in Portuguese: Comércio
internacional
exported in Romanian: Comerţ internaţional
exported in Russian: Международная
торговля
exported in Urdu: بین الاقوامی تجارت
exported in Chinese: 国际贸易
exported in Polish: handel zagraniczny
exported in Turkish: Uluslararası
ticaret