Dictionary Definition
delegation
Noun
2 authorizing subordinates to make certain
decisions [syn: delegating, relegating, relegation, deputation]
User Contributed Dictionary
see Delegation
English
Pronunciation
-
- Rhymes: -eɪʃǝn
Noun
- An act of delegating.
- A group of delegates used to discuss issues with an opponent.
- : A method dispatching technique describing the lookup and
inheritance rules for self-referential calls.
- A contract whereby the original debtor substitutes a new debtor in his stead, with the creditor’s permission.
Translations
- German: Delegation
- Hebrew: משלחת (mishlakhat) (2)
- Spanish: delegación
See also
Extensive Definition
It is the assignment of authority and
responsibility to another person (normally from a manager to a
subordinate) to carry out specific activities. However the person
who delegated the work remains accountable for the outcome of the
delegate work. It allows a subordinate to make decisions, i.e. it
is a shift of decision-making authority from one organizational
level to a lower one. Delegation, if properly done, is not abdication. The opposite of
effective delegation is micromanagement, where a
manager provides too much input, direction, and review of
'delegated' work.
Delegation Theories
types of delegation- Allocating authority to issue orders.
- Entrusting tasks to subordinates.
- Allocating decision making in defined areas.
Principal - Agent Theory
Principal-Agent theory conceives of delegation as
involving firstly a 'principal' who for a particular reason decides
to delegate authority over a particular policy area (for example)
to another actor or organisation - the 'agent'. It is generally
conceived of as more of a framework than a predictive theory and it
incorporates a wide variety of forms. Generally speaking there have
been two areas of primary focus, firstly that concerned with
'agency loss' which roughly corresponds to the extent to which
decisions/policy outcomes arrived at by the agent differ from the
goals of the principal. This in turn leads to theories concerning
how to minimise agency loss whilst maintaining the benefits of
delegation. Such theories tend to emphasise the use of ex ante and
ex post
controls which can help ensure compliance, though every
principal-agent approach stresses that principals and agents always
have separate interests and as such a beneficial delegation will
always result in some element of agency loss.
Secondly there is the focus on 'informational
asymmetries' whereby the agent is assumed to possess an advantage
in terms of expertise in the particular area which it is delegated
authority in. For instance if a local government decided to
delegate refuse collection to a private firm, after a suitable
amount of time the private firm would possess expertise in this
area that would put it in an advantageous position relative to the
principal. As such the agent could use this informational advantage
to shape the relations between themselves and the principal to
achieve more favourable outcomes - for instance the principal in
this example may not know exactly how much funds are required to
carry out the task of refuse collection effectively and will rely
on the agent to provide them with this information, as such the
agent is given the opportunity to extract more funds than is
necessary to carry out the task.
Carltona Principle
Used by the UK civil service. In summary the
principle supports delegation of authority but not
responsibility.
Section 1 of the civil service act 1992 allows
delegation to take place, but limits the powers to do so in three
ways -
- the functions to be delegated must be management functions;
- they must have been the subject of Transfer of Functions Orders; and
- they must relate to the management of the Civil Service.
Most delegations are made under this section of
the Act. However for the minority of civil servants whose terms and
conditions of service are determined under powers in primary
legislation which govern the organisations in which they work
Section 2 of the ACt applies. The statutes in these cases usually
require Ministers and statutory office holders to obtain the
consent of the Minister for the Civil Service to the terms and
conditions of their staff. The Civil Service (Management Functions)
Act 1992 allows the Minister for the Civil Service to authorise the
exercise of these powers without his consent. The policy has been
to delegate to Ministers who can then authorise an official (e.g.
Permanent Secretary, Chief Executive) to exercise the function in
his name under the Carltona principle.
The Principle allows a person in whom a power is
vested to authorise another person to exercise that power for and
on his or her behalf. It is essential to note at the outset that a
person exercising a power for and on behalf of another does so as
the ‘agent’ or ‘alter ego’ of the person in whom the power is
vested. That is, the act of the authorised person is, at law, the
act of the person in whom the power is vested. This is
fundamentally different from the act of a delegate which, at law,
is the delegate’s and not the delegator’s act.
The case most often cited as authority for the
proposition that a person may authorise another to exercise a power
for and on his or her behalf is Carltona Ltd v Commissioners of
Works 1943. This was a wartime case dealing with the requisition by
the Government of a factory which manufactured food products. In
Carltona, the English Court of Appeal considered whether a Minister
had to exercise personally a power to take possession of land, or
whether the power could be exercised by one of the Minister’s
departmental officials for and on behalf of the Minister.
The court concluded that the power in question
could be exercised by a departmental official for and on behalf of
the Minister. The court’s reasoning indicates that there are two
grounds which justify a Minister being able to authorise an officer
to exercise a power vested in the Minister -
the Minister is ultimately responsible to
Parliament for the decision of an authorised officer; and in modern
government, Ministers have so many functions and powers that
administrative necessity dictates that they act through duly
authorised officers.
Delegation as a credible commitment
This section of the literature has purported to
explain delegation as a solution to the problem of 'credible
commitments'. In short this states that in certain situations an
actor will choose to delegate authority to another actor or
organisation in order to constrain their own behaviour and provide
credibility to a particular obligation they have entered into. To
give one of the sillier examples present in the literature there is
that of three blind men left alone in a room with a cake. They all
enter into a pact that none of them will eat the cake, but as
nobody is capable of enforcing this agreement they decide to
delegate authority to one of their friends who can watch over them
to ensure nobody breaks their commitment and sneaks off with a
slice. In this way delegating authority is seen as overcoming
collective action problems.
This theory has been applied most prominently in
the context of democratic pressures which impact on a government's
ability to uphold international agreements. Two factors are seen as
causing this problem, firstly the problem of 'time inconsistency'
whereby what is the best short-term solution to a problem may be
different from the optimal long-term solution. In this instance a
government may agree to carry out the long term course of action,
but when faced with the pressures of winning an election will
resort to the short term course of action which undermines the
agreement. To overcome this problem the government will delegate
authority to an actor or organisation so as to ensure that the
correct long term policy is carried out even when it is not
electorally desirable. Secondly there is the problem of 'political
property rights' which refers to the fact that as democracies have
the potential to replace one government with another government who
support opposing policies, the agreements made by one government
must be somehow enforced by an independent authority so that they
constrain future governments from breaking them.
Applications of Delegation Theory
Independent Central Banks and Non Majoritarian Institutions
One of the most important areas where delegation
theories have been applied has been in the debate over the merits
of Independent Central Banks (ICBs) such as the Bank of
England or the European
Central Bank. This debate has corresponded to the theories of
credible commitments and can be understood as a solution to
problems posed by the two democratic pressure problems mentioned
above where monetary
policy is concerned. Those in favour of the creation of ICBs
have primarily focused on interest
rates and have argued that democratic pressures tend to have an
inflationary effect
as governments will often be tempted to advocate higher interest
rates immediately prior to an election so as to manufacture short
term booms in the economy and boost their support - but to the
detriment of long term economic health. A variant of this argument
is that as most democracies incorporate two main parties split on
economic policy between left and right, the party of the left
winning power will often result in damaging inflation raising
policies immediately after the election in an effort to distance
itself from the previous government. A solution to these problems
has naturally been sought in the creation of an independent
institution which can decide interest rates outside of the
influence of democratic pressures - the ICB.
This argument has been highly influential and the
number of ICBs has risen dramatically since the 1980s however it is
not without its critics. Many scholars (for instance Kathleen
Mcnamara) have questioned the premisses of the ICB argument, making
the case that democratic pressures will not result in high
inflation and that high inflation is not inherently bad for the
economy long term. Broadly speaking the empirical evidence on these
points has tended to be inconclusive for both sides. An alternative
criticism has come from certain branches of New
institutionalism who have sought to explain the increase in
ICBs not by the 'rational' argument outlined above, but as a
process of symbolism, where governments will create ICBs because
they are seen to be respectable institutions by other actors,
particularly by foreign investors who, it is argued, will view a
country with an ICB as a modern state worthy of investment.
The European Union
Delegation theories have also been applied
extensively in studies of the European
Union. The dominant approach has undoubtedly been the
principal-agent approach, but there have also been variations from
the classic form by intergovernmentalist
approaches and the 'fiduciary' model laid out by
Giandomenico
Majone.
Andrew
Moravcsik is perhaps the most prominent intergovernmentalist
theorist who has written on delegation and his work can essentially
be thought of as applying the principal-agent model in a manner
which stresses minimal agency loss. The model is not a simple
principal-agent model however, as he conceives of the EU as
delegation on three levels. Firstly there is the delegation from
European electorates to national governments (who in this sense act
as agents), secondly there is the delegation from national
governments (who now act as principals) to European institutions
such as the European
Commission. Moravcsik has been particularly interested in the
informational asymmetries which arise from delegation in the
European Union and has argued that whilst there is minimal agency
loss between the national governments and the European
institutions, the national governments gain significant
informational advantages over European electorates which allow them
to carry out policies at home which they would not be able to do in
the absence of the European Union. In this sense the delegation
process strengthens the national governments rather than weakening
them (as is traditionally assumed where the European Union is
concerned). This has nevertheless been seen as inconsistent by some
scholars (for instance Mark Pollack) who take issue with the
assertion that informational advantages only allow national
governments to gain freedom from European electorates and that the
same principle applies with European institutions gaining an
advantage over their principals through informational
asymmetries.
In contrast Giandomenico Majone has formulated a
theory of delegation which stresses the importance of credibility
problems in the decision to delegate to European institutions. Not
only is this explained as a mechanism to ensure member states
comply with treaty obligations, but employing similar logic as that
used in the ICB debates he makes a defence against democratic
deficit arguments which advocate a directly elected European
Commission. Much in the same way as in the ICB debate democratic
pressures are seen as impacting negatively on what is a primarily
regulatory institution and as such for Majone the Commission should
be insulated from democratic pressures if it is to fulfil its
functions effectively.
References
- Fabrizio Gilardi, "The same, but different. Central banks, regulatory agencies,
- Giandomenico Majone, "Two Logics of Delegation: Agency and Fiduciary Relations in EU Governance" European Union Politics.2001; 2: 103-122
- Kathleen Mcnamara, "Rational Fictions: Central Bank Independence and the Social Logic of Delegation" West European Politics, 25 (1)
- Andrew Moravcsik, "The Choice for Europe"
External links
delegation in German: Delegation
delegation in Japanese: 委任
delegation in Norwegian: Delegasjon
delegation in Swedish: Delegering
Synonyms, Antonyms and Related Words
accession, agency, agentship, anointing, anointment, appointment, arrogation, assignment, assumption, authority, authorization, brevet, care, change, charge, commendation, commission, commissioning, commitment, committee, commutation, consecration, consignment, coronation, cure, delegated authority, deputation, deputyship, devolution, devolvement, displacement, election, embassy, empowerment, enfeoffment, entrusting, entrustment, errand, exchange, executorship, exequatur, factorship, full power,
infeodation,
infeudation,
jurisdiction,
legation, legitimate
succession, license,
lieutenancy,
mandate, mission, office, plenipotentiary power,
power of attorney, power to act, procuration, proxy, purview, quid pro quo, regency, regentship, relegation, remanding, replacement, representation, responsibility, seizure, subcommittee, subrogation, substitution, succession, supersedence, superseding, supersedure, supersession, supplantation, supplanting, supplantment, switch, taking over, task, tit for tat, trust, trusteeship, usurpation, vicarious
authority, vicariousness, warrant