Dictionary Definition
bureaucracy n : nonelective government officials
[syn: bureaucratism]
User Contributed Dictionary
English
Noun
- Structure and regulations in place to control activity. Usually in large organizations and government operations.
Translations
structure and regulations in place to control
activity
- Chinese: 官僚 (guān liáo)
- Estonian: bürokraatia
- Finnish: byrokratia, hallintokoneisto
- French: bureaucratie
- German: Bürokratie
- Hebrew: ביורוקרטיה (biuroqrat'ia)
- Hungarian: bürokrácia
- Icelandic: skrifræði, skrifstofuveldi
- Japanese: 官僚機構 (kanryō-kikou)
- Malay: birokrasi
- Norwegian: byråkrati
- Portuguese: burocracia
- Russian: бюрократия
- Swedish: byråkrati
- Telugu: అధికార వర్గం (adhikaara vargaM)
Derived terms
Extensive Definition
Bureaucracy is the structure and set of
regulations in place to control activity, usually in large
organizations and government. As opposed to adhocracy, it is represented
by standardized procedure (rule-following) that dictates the
execution of most or all processes within the body, formal division
of powers, hierarchy, and relationships. In practice the
interpretation and execution of policy can lead to informal
influence.
Bureaucracy is a concept in sociology and political
science referring to the way that the administrative execution
and enforcement of legal rules are socially organized. Four
structural concepts are central to any definition of bureaucracy:
- a well-defined division of administrative labor among persons and offices,
- a personnel system with consistent patterns of recruitment and stable linear careers,
- a hierarchy among offices, such that the authority and status are differentially distributed among actors, and
- formal and informal networks that connect organizational actors to one another through flows of information and patterns of cooperation.
Examples of everyday bureaucracies include
governments, armed forces,
corporations,
hospitals, courts,
ministries and schools.
Origin of the concept
The word "bureaucracy" stems from the word "bureau", used from the early 18th century in Western Europe not just to refer to a writing desk, but to an office, i.e., a workplace, where officials worked. The original French meaning of the word bureau was the baize used to cover desks. The term bureaucracy came into use shortly before the French Revolution of 1789, and from there rapidly spread to other countries. The Greek suffix - kratia or kratos - means "power" or "rule".In a letter of July 1, 1790, the German
Baron von Grimm declared: "We are obsessed by the idea of
regulation, and our Masters of Requests refuse to understand that
there is an infinity of things in a great state with which a
government should not concern itself."
Jean Claude Marie Vincent de Gournay sometimes used to say, "We
have an illness in France which bids fair to play havoc with us;
this illness is called bureaumania." Sometimes he used to invent a
fourth or fifth form of government under the heading of
"bureaucracy".
In another letter of July 15, 1765 Baron Grimm
wrote also, "The real spirit of the laws in France is that
bureaucracy of which the late Monsieur de Gournay used to complain
so greatly; here the offices, clerks, secretaries, inspectors and
intendants are not appointed to benefit the public interest, indeed
the public interest appears to have been established so that
offices might exist."
This quote refers to a traditional controversy
about bureaucracy, namely the perversion of means and ends so that
means become ends in themselves, and the greater good is lost sight
of; as a corollary, the substitution of sectional interests for the
general interest. The suggestion here is that, left uncontrolled,
the bureaucracy will become increasingly self-serving and corrupt,
rather than serving society.
Development of Bureaucracy
Perhaps the early example of a bureaucrat is the scribe, who first arose as a professional in the early cities of Sumer. The Sumerian script was so complicated that it required specialists who had trained for their entire lives in the discipline of writing to manipulate it. These scribes could wield significant power, as they had a total monopoly on the keeping of records and creation of inscriptions on monuments to kings.In later, larger empires like Achaemenid
Persia, bureaucracies quickly expanded as government expanded
and increased its functions. In the Persian Empire, the central
government was divided into administrative provinces led by satraps. The satraps were
appointed by the Shah to control the
provinces. In addition, a general and a royal secretary were stationed in
each province to supervise troop recruitment and keep records,
respectively. The Achaemenid Great Kings also sent royal inspectors
to tour the empire and report on local conditions.
The most modernesque of
all ancient bureaucracies, however, was the Chinese
bureaucracy. During the chaos of the Spring
and Autumn Period and the Warring
States, Confucius
recognized the need for a stable system of administrators to lend
good governance even when the leaders were inept. Chinese
bureaucracy, first implemented during the Qin dynasty
but under more Confucian
lines under the Han, calls
for the appointment of bureaucratic positions based on merit via a system of
examinations.
Although the power of the Chinese bureaucrats waxed and waned
throughout China's long history,
the imperial examination system lasted as late as 1905, and modern China
still employs a formidable bureaucracy in its daily workings.
Modern bureaucracies arose as the government of
states grew larger during the modern period, and especially
following the Industrial
Revolution. Tax collectors,
perhaps the most reviled of all bureaucrats, became increasingly
necessary as states began to take in more and more revenue, while
the role of administrators increased as the functions of government
multiplied. Along with this expansion, though, came the recognition
of the corruption
and nepotism often
inherent within the managerial system, leading to
civil service reform on a large scale in many countries towards
the end of the 19th
century.
Entrepreneurship, Networked Legitimacy, and Autonomy
In "The Forging of Bureaucratic Autonomy," Daniel Carpenter argues that bureaucratic autonomy emerges only upon the historical achievement of three conditions:- the autonomous bureaucracies are politically differentiated from the actors who seek to control them.
- the bureaucratic autonomy requires the development of unique organizational capacities - capacities to analyze, to create new programs, to solve problems, to plan, to administer programs with efficiency, and to ward off corruption.
- bureaucratic autonomy requires political legitimacy, or strong organizational reputations embedded in an independent power base.
Karl Marx and bureaucracy
In Karl Marx's and Friedrich Engels's theory of historical materialism, the historical origin of bureaucracy is to be found in four sources: religion, the formation of the state, commerce and technology.Thus, the earliest bureaucracies consisted of
castes of religious clergy, officials and scribes operating various
rituals, and armed functionaries specifically delegated to keep
order. In the historical transition from primitive egalitarian
communities to a civil society divided into social classes and
estates, beginning from about 10,000 years ago, authority is
increasingly centralized in, and enforced by a state apparatus
existing separately from society. This state formulates, imposes
and enforces laws, and levies taxes, giving rise to an officialdom
enacting these functions. Thus, the state mediates in conflicts
among the people and keeps those conflicts within acceptable
bounds; it also organizes the defense of territory. Most
importantly, the right of ordinary people to carry and use weapons
of force becomes increasingly restricted; in civil society, forcing
other people to do things becomes increasingly the legal right of
the state authorities only.
But the growth of trade and commerce adds a new,
distinctive dimension to bureaucracy, insofar as it requires the
keeping of accounts and the processing/recording of transactions,
as well as the enforcement of legal rules governing trade. If
resources are increasingly distributed by prices in markets, this requires
extensive and complex systems of record-keeping, management and
calculation, conforming to legal standards. Eventually, this means
that the total amount of work involved in commercial administration
outgrows the total amount of work involved in government
administration. In modern capitalist society, private sector
bureaucracy is larger than government bureaucracy, if measured by
the number of administrative workers in the division
of labor as a whole. Some corporations nowadays have a turnover
larger than the national income of whole countries, with large
administrations supervising operations.
A fourth source of bureaucracy Marxists have
commented on inheres in the technologies of mass production, which
require many standardized routines and procedures to be performed.
Even if mechanization replaces people with machinery, people are
still necessary to design, control, supervise and operate the
machinery. The technologies chosen may not be the ones that are
best for everybody, but which create incomes for a particular class
of people or maintain their power. This type of bureaucracy is
nowadays often called a technocracy,
which owes its power to control over specialized technical
knowledge or control over critical information.
In Marx's theory, bureaucracy rarely creates new
wealth by itself, but rather controls, co-ordinates and governs the
production, distribution and consumption of wealth. The bureaucracy
as a social stratum derives its income from the appropriation of
part of the social surplus
product of human labor. Wealth is appropriated by the
bureaucracy by law through fees, taxes, levies, tributes, licensing
etc.
Bureaucracy is therefore always a cost to
society, but this cost may be accepted insofar as it makes social order
possible, and maintains it by enforcing the rule of law.
Nevertheless there are constant conflicts about this cost, because
it has the big effect on the distribution of incomes; all producers
will try to get the maximum return from what they produce, and
minimize administrative costs. Typically, in epochs of strong
economic growth, bureaucracies proliferate; when economic growth
declines, a fight breaks out to cut back bureaucratic costs.
Whether or not a bureaucracy as a social stratum
can become a genuine ruling class
depends greatly on the prevailing property relations and the
mode of
production of wealth. In capitalist society, the state
typically lacks an independent economic base, finances many
activities on credit, and is heavily dependent on levying taxes as
a source of income. Therefore, its power is limited by the costs
which private owners of the productive assets will tolerate. If,
however, the state owns the means
of production itself, defended by military power, the state
bureaucracy can become much more powerful, and act as a ruling
class or power elite. Because in that case, it directly controls
the sources of new wealth, and manages or distributes the social
product. This is the subject of Marxist theories of bureaucratic
collectivism.
Marx himself however never theorized this
possibility in detail, and it has been the subject of much
controversy among Marxists. The core organizational issue in these
disputes concerns the degree to which the administrative allocation
of resources by government authorities and the market allocation of
resources can achieve the social goal of creating a more free, just
and prosperous society. Which decisions should be made by whom, at
what level, so that an optimal allocation of resources results?
This is just as much a moral-political issue as an economic
issue.
Central to the Marxian concept of socialism is the idea of
workers' self-management, which assumes the internalization of a
morality and
self-discipline among people that would make bureaucratic
supervision and control redundant, together with a drastic
reorganization of the division of labor in society. Bureaucracies
emerge to mediate conflicts of interest on the basis of laws, but
if those conflicts of interest disappear (because resources are
allocated directly in a fair way), bureaucracies would also be
redundant.
Marx's critics are however skeptical of the
feasibility of this kind of socialism, given the continuing need
for administration and the rule of law, as well as the propensity
of people to put their own self-interest before the communal
interest. That is, the argument is that self-interest and the
communal interest might never coincide, or, at any rate, can always
diverge significantly.
Max Weber on bureaucracy
Max Weber has probably been one of the most influential users of the word in its social science sense. He is well-known for his study of bureaucratization of society; many aspects of modern public administration go back to him; a classic, hierarchically organized civil service of the continental type is — if perhaps mistakenly — called "Weberian civil service".However, contrary to popular belief,
"bureaucracy" was an English
word before Weber; the Oxford
English Dictionary cites usage in several different years
between 1818
and 1860,
prior to Weber's birth in 1864.
Weber described the ideal type
bureaucracy in positive terms, considering it to be a more rational
and efficient form of organization than the alternatives that
preceded it, which he characterized as charismatic
domination and traditional
domination. According to his terminology, bureaucracy is part
of legal
domination. However, he also emphasized that bureaucracy
becomes inefficient when a decision must be adopted to an
individual case.
According to Weber, the attributes of modern
bureaucracy include its impersonality, concentration of the means
of administration, a leveling effect on social and economic
differences and implementation of a system of authority that is
practically indestructible.
Weber's analysis of bureaucracy concerns:
- the historical and administrative reasons for the process of bureaucratization (especially in the Western civilisation)
- the impact of the rule of law upon the functioning of bureaucratic organisations
- the typical personal orientation and occupational position of a bureaucratic officials as a status group
- the most important attributes and consequences of bureaucracy in the modern world
A bureaucratic organization is governed by the
following seven principles:
- official business is conducted on a continuous basis
- official business is conducted with strict accordance to the
following rules:
- the duty of each official to do certain types of work is delimited in terms of impersonal criteria
- the official is given the authority necessary to carry out his assigned functions
- the means of coercion at his disposal are strictly limited and conditions of their use strictly defined
- every official's responsibilities and authority are part of a vertical hierarchy of authority, with respective rights of supervision and appeal
- officials do not own the resources necessary for the performance of their assigned functions but are accountable for their use of these resources
- official and private business and income are strictly separated
- offices cannot be appropriated by their incumbents (inherited, sold, etc.)
- official business is conducted on the basis of written documents
A bureaucratic official:
- is personally free and appointed to his position on the basis of conduct
- exercises the authority delegated to him in accordance with impersonal rules, and his or her loyalty is enlisted on behalf of the faithful execution of his official duties
- appointment and job placement are dependent upon his or her technical qualifications
- administrative work is a full-time occupation
- work is rewarded by a regular salary and prospects of advancement in a lifetime career
An official must exercise his or her judgment and
his or her skills, but his or her duty is to place these at the
service of a higher authority; ultimately he/she is responsible
only for the impartial execution of assigned tasks and must
sacrifice his or her personal judgment if it runs counter to his or
her official duties.
Weber's work has been continued by many, like
Robert
Michels with his Iron
Law of Oligarchy.
Criticism
As Max Weber himself noted, real bureaucracy will be less optimal and effective than his ideal type model. Each of Weber's seven principles can degenerate:- Vertical hierarchy of authority can become chaotic, some offices can be omitted in the decision making process, there may be conflicts of competence;
- Competences can be unclear and used contrary to the spirit of the law; sometimes a decision itself may be considered more important than its effect;
- Nepotism, corruption, political infighting and other degenerations can counter the rule of impersonality and can create a recruitment and promotion system not based on meritocracy but rather on oligarchy;
- Officials try to avoid accountability and seek anonymity by avoiding documentation of their procedures (or creating extreme amounts of chaotic, confusing documents, see also: transparency)
Even a non-degenerated bureaucracy can be
affected by common problems:
- Overspecialization, making individual officials not aware of larger consequences of their actions
- Rigidity and inertia of procedures, making decision-making slow or even impossible when facing some unusual case, and similarly delaying change, evolution and adaptation of old procedures to new circumstances;
- A phenomenon of group thinking - zealotry, loyalty and lack of critical thinking regarding the organisation which is perfect and always correct by definition, making the organisation unable to change and realise its own mistakes and limitations;
- Disregard for dissenting opinions, even when such views suit the available data better than the opinion of the majority;
- A phenomenon of Catch-22 (named after a famous book by Joseph Heller) - as bureaucracy creates more and more rules and procedures, their complexity rises and coordination diminishes, facilitating creation of contradictory and recursive rules
- Not allowing people to use common sense, as everything must be as is written by the law.
In the most common examples bureaucracy can lead
to the treatment of individual human beings as impersonal objects.
This process has been criticised by many philosophers and writers
(Aldous
Huxley, George
Orwell, Hannah
Arendt) and satirized in the comic strip Dilbert,TV show
The
Office, Franz Kafka's
novels The
Trial and The
Castle , Douglas
Adams' story
The Hitchhiker's Guide to the Galaxy, and the films Brazil and
Office
Space''.
...[A]dministration in the United States must be
at all points sensitive to public opinion. A body of thoroughly
trained officials serving during good behavior we must have in any
case: that is a plain business necessity. But the apprehension that
such a body will be anything un-American clears away the moment it
is asked. What is to constitute good behavior? For that question
obviously carries its own answer on its face. Steady, hearty
allegiance to the policy of the government they serve will
constitute good behavior. That policy will have no taint of
officialism about it. It will not be the creation of permanent
officials, but of statesmen whose responsibility to public opinion
will be direct and inevitable. Bureaucracy can exist only where the
whole service of the state is removed from the common political
life of the people, its chiefs as well as its rank and file. Its
motives, its objects, its policy, its standards, must be
bureaucratic.
Nevertheless, American colloquial usage is
usually derogatory unless established otherwise. An example might
be that an organization which puts its own comfort, convenience and
longevity ahead of its mission could be called a bureaucracy.
It is no wonder that popular dictionary
definitions echo our profound dislike of bureaucracy. The American
Heritage Dictionary definition of bureaucracy reads in part:
"numerous offices and adherence to inflexible rules of
operation;... any unwieldy administration." According to Webster's
New world Dictionary of the American Language, "bureaucracy is
governmental officialism or inflexible routine." Roget's Thesaurus
gives equally demeaning synonyms for bureaucracy: "officialism",
"officiousness", and "red tape".
Austrian School Analysis of Bureaucracy
The analysis of bureaucracy by the Austrian school reflects its characteristic focus on economics, and emphasizes the distinction between bureaucratic management and profit management.Current academic debates
Modern academic research has debated the extent to which elected officials can control their bureaucratic agents. Because bureaucrats have more information than elected officials about what they are doing and what they should be doing, bureaucrats might have the ability to implement policies or regulations that go against the public interest. In the American context, these concerns led to the "Congressional abdication" hypotheses--the claim that Congress had abdicated its authority over public policy to appointed bureaucrats.Theodore Lowi initiated this debate by concluding
in a 1979 book that the U.S. Congress does not exercise effective
oversight of bureaucratic agencies. Instead, policies are made by
"iron
triangles", consisting of interest
groups, appointed bureaucrats, and
Congressional subcommittees (who, according to Lowi, were
likely to have more extreme views than the Congress as a whole). It
is thought that since 1979 interest groups have taken a large role
and now do not only effect bureaucracy, but also the money in
congress. The idea of "iron triangles" has since evolved to "iron
hexagons" and then to a "hollow sphere."
The relationships between the Legislatures, the
Interest Groups, Bureaucrats, and the general public all have an
effect on each other. Without one of these pieces the entire
structure would completely change. This relationship is considered
"mu", or such that not one single piece can describe or control the
entire process. The public votes in the legislatures and the
interest groups provide information, but the legislature and
bureaucrats also have an effect on the interest groups and the
public. The entire system is codependent on each other.
William
Niskanen's earlier (1971) 'budget-maximizing'
model complemented Lowi's claims; where Lowi claimed that
Congress (and legislatures more generally) failed to exercise
oversight, Niskanen argued that rational bureaucrats will always
and everywhere seek to increase their budgets, thereby contributing
strongly to state growth. Niskanen went on to serve on the U.S.
Council of Economic Advisors under President Reagan, and his model
provided a strong underpinning for the worldwide move towards
cutbacks of public spending and the introduction of privatization
in the 1980s and '90s.
Two branches of theorizing have arisen in
response to these claims. The first focuses on bureaucratic
motivations; Niskanen's universalist approach was critiqued by a
range of pluralist authors who argued that officials' motivations
are more public interest-orientated than Niskanen allowed. The
bureau-shaping
model (put forward by Patrick
Dunleavy) also argues against Niskanen that rational
bureaucrats should only maximize the part of their budget that they
spend on their own agency's operations or give to contractors or
powerful interest groups (that are able to organize a flowback of
benefits to senior officials). For instance, rational officials
will get no benefit from paying out larger welfare checks to
millions of poor people, since the bureaucrats' own utilities are
not improved. Consequently we should expect bureaucracies to
significantly maximize budgets in areas like police forces and
defense, but not in areas like welfare state spending.
A second branch of responses has focused more on
Lowi's claims, asking whether legislatures (and usually the
American Congress in particular) can control bureaucrats. This
empirical research is motivated by a normative concern: If we wish
to believe that we live in a democracy, then it must be
true that appointed bureaucrats cannot act contrary to elected
officials' interests. (This claim is itself debatable; if we fully
trusted elected officials, we would not spend so much time
implementing constitutional checks and balances.)
Within this second branch, scholars have
published numerous studies debating the circumstances under which
elected officials can control bureaucratic outputs. Most of these
studies examine the American case, though their findings have been
generalized elsewhere as well. These studies argue that
legislatures have a variety of oversight means at their disposal,
and they use many of them regularly. These oversight mechanisms
have been classified into two types: "Police patrols" (actively
auditing agencies and looking for misbehavior) and "fire alarms"
(imposing open administrative procedures on bureaucrats to make it
easier for adversely affected groups to detect bureaucratic
malfeasance and bring it to the legislature's attention).
A third concept of self-interested bureaucracy
and its effect on the production of public goods
has been forwarded by Faizul
Latif Chowdhury. In contrast to Niskanen and Dunleavy, who
primarily focused on the self-interested behaviour of only the
top-level bureaucrats involved in policy making, Chowdhury in his
thesis submitted to the
London School of Economics in 1997 drew attention to the impact
of the low level civil servants whose rent-seeking behaviour pushes
up the cost of production of public goods. Particularly, it was
shown with reference to the tax officials how rent-seeking by them
causes loss in government revenue. Chowdhury’s model of rent-seeking
bureaucracy captures the case of administrative corruption
whereby public money is directly expropriated by public servants in
general.
Sources
- On Karl Marx: Hal Draper, Karl Marx's Theory of Revolution, Volume 1: State and Bureaucracy. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1979.
- Marx comments on the state bureaucracy in his Critique of Hegel's Philosophy of Right http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1843/critique-hpr/index.htm and Engels discusses the origins of the state here: http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1884/origin-family/index.htm
- Ernest Mandel, Power and Money: A Marxist Theory of Bureaucracy. London: Verso, 1992.
- On Weber: Sociology, Work and Industry
- Neil Garston (ed.), Bureaucracy: Three Paradigms. Boston: Kluwer, 1993.
- Chowdhury, Faizul Latif (2006), Corrupt Bureaucracy and Privatization of Tax Enforcement. Dhaka: Pathak Samabesh, ISBN 984-8120-62-9.
References
External links
- Abstracts of academic books and articles about bureaucracy
- Kevin R. Kosar, "What Ought a Bureaucrat Do?" Claremont.org, (A review piece that ponders the values that should guide bureaucrats in their work.)
- Corrupt Bureaucracy and Privatization of Tax Enforcement in Bangladesh by Faizul Latif Chowdhury
See also
bureaucracy in Arabic: بيروقراطية
bureaucracy in Bulgarian: Бюрокрация
bureaucracy in Czech: Byrokracie
bureaucracy in Danish: Bureaukrati
bureaucracy in German: Bürokratie
bureaucracy in Estonian: Bürokraatia
bureaucracy in Spanish: Burocracia
bureaucracy in Persian: دیوانسالاری
bureaucracy in French: Bureaucratie
bureaucracy in Galician: Burocracia
bureaucracy in Indonesian: Birokrasi
bureaucracy in Icelandic: Skrifræði
bureaucracy in Italian: Burocrazia
bureaucracy in Hebrew: ביורוקרטיה
bureaucracy in Georgian: ბიუროკრატია
bureaucracy in Lithuanian: Biurokratija
bureaucracy in Malay (macrolanguage):
Birokrasi
bureaucracy in Dutch: Bureaucratie
bureaucracy in Japanese: 官僚制
bureaucracy in Norwegian: Byråkrati
bureaucracy in Polish: Biurokracja
bureaucracy in Portuguese: Burocracia
bureaucracy in Russian: Бюрократия
bureaucracy in Simple English: Bureaucracy
bureaucracy in Slovak: Byrokracia
bureaucracy in Slovenian: Birokratizem
bureaucracy in Serbian: Бирократија
bureaucracy in Finnish: Byrokratia
bureaucracy in Swedish: Byråkrati
bureaucracy in Turkish: Bürokrasi
bureaucracy in Ukrainian: Бюрократія
bureaucracy in Urdu: دفتری حکومت
bureaucracy in Chinese: 官僚制
Synonyms, Antonyms and Related Words
administration, authorities, beadledom, beat, beaten path, bumbledom, bureaucratism, chinoiserie, daily grind,
directorate,
government, grind, groove, hierarchy, higher echelons,
higher-ups, jog trot, management, ministry, official jargon,
officialdom,
officialism,
prelacy, red tape,
red-tapeism, red-tapery, round, routine, ruling class, ruling
classes, run, rut, squirrel cage, the
Establishment, the administration, the authorities, the ingroup,
the interests, the people upstairs, the power elite, the power
structure, the top, them,
they, top brass, track, treadmill, well-worn
groove