Dictionary Definition
antitrust adj : of laws and regulations; designed
to protect trade and commerce from unfair business practices [syn:
antimonopoly]
User Contributed Dictionary
English
Adjective
- Opposed to or against the establishment or existence of
trusts (monopolies), usually referring
to legislation.
- The regulators used antitrust laws to block the merger, believing it would eliminate competition.
Translations
See also
Usage notes
- In the United States, laws that prohibit monopolies are called antitrust laws; in other parts of the world, such laws are generally referred to as antimonopoly laws or competition laws.
Extensive Definition
An early example of competition law is the Lex
Julia de Annona, enacted during the Roman
Republic around 50 BC. To protect the corn trade, heavy fines
were imposed on anyone directly, deliberately and insidiously
stopping supply ships. Under Diocletian in
301 AD an edict
imposed the death penalty for anyone violating a tariff system, for
example by buying up, concealing or contriving the scarcity of
everyday goods.
More legislation came under the Constitution of
Zeno of 483
AD, which can be traced into Florentine Municipal laws of 1322 and
1325. This provided for confiscation of property and banishment for
any trade combinations or joint action of monopolies private or
granted by the Emperor. Zeno rescinded all
previously granted exclusive rights. Justinian I
subsequently introduced legislation to pay officials to manage
state monopolies. As Europe slipped into the dark ages, so
did the records of law making until the Middle Ages brought greater
expansion of trade in the time of lex
mercatoria.
Middle ages
Legislation in England to control monopolies and restrictive practices were in force well before the Norman Conquest. The Domesday Book recorded that "foresteel" (i.e. forestalling, the practice of buying up goods before they reach market and then inflating the prices) was one of three forfeitures that King Edward the Confessor could carry out through England. But concern for fair prices also led to attempts to directly regulate the market. Under Henry III an act was passed in 1266 to fix bread and ale prices in correspondence with corn prices laid down by the assizes. Penalties for breach included amercements, pillory and tumbrel. A fourteenth century statute labelled forestallers as "oppressors of the poor and the community at large and enemies of the whole country." Under King Edward III the Statute of Labourers of 1349 fixed wages of artificers and workmen and decreed that foodstuffs should be sold at reasonable prices. On top of existing penalties, the statute stated that overcharging merchants must pay the injured party double the sum he received, an idea that has been replicated in punitive treble damages under US antitrust law. Also under Edward III, the following statutory provision outlawed trade combinations."...we have ordained and established, that no
merchant or other shall make Confederacy, Conspiracy, Coin,
Imagination, or Murmur, or Evil Device in any point that may turn
to the Impeachment, Disturbance, Defeating or Decay of the said
Staples, or of anything that to them pertaineth, or may
pertain."
Examples of legislation in mainland Europe
include the constitutiones juris metallici by Wenceslas II
of Bohemia
between 1283 and 1305, condemning combinations of ore traders
increasing prices; the Municipal Statutes of Florence in 1322 and
1325 followed Zeno's legislation
against state monopolies; and under Emperor
Charles V in the Holy
Roman Empire a law was passed "to prevent losses resulting from
monopolies and improper contracts which many merchants and artisans
made in the Netherlands." In 1553 King Henry
VIII reintroduced tariffs for foodstuffs, designed to stabilise
prices, in the face of fluctuations in supply from overseas. So the
legislation read here that whereas,
"it is very hard and difficult to put certain
prices to any such things... [it is necessary because] prices of
such victuals be many times enhanced and raised by the Greedy
Covetousness and Appetites of the Owners of such Victuals, by
occasion of ingrossing and regrating the same, more than upon any
reasonable or just ground or cause, to the great damage and
impoverishing of the King's subjects."
Around this time organisations representing
various tradesmen and handicraftspeople, known as guilds had been developing, and
enjoyed many concessions and exemptions from the laws against
monopolies. The privileges conferred were not abolished until the
Municipal Corporations Act 1835.
Renaissance developments
seealso Renaissance Europe around the 15th century was changing fast. The new world had just been opened up, overseas trade and plunder was pouring wealth through the international economy and attitudes among businessmen were shifting. In 1561 a system of Industrial Monopoly Licences, similar to modern patents had been introduced into England. But by the reign of Queen Elizabeth I, the system was reputedly much abused and used merely to preserve privileges, encouraging nothing new in the way of innovation or manufacture. When a protest was made in the House of Commons and a Bill was introduced, the Queen convinced the protesters to challenge the case in the courts. This was the catalyst for the Case of Monopolies or Darcy v. Allin. The plaintiff, an officer of the Queen's household, had been granted the sole right of making playing cards and claimed damages for the defendant's infringement of this right. The court found the grant void and that three characteristics of monopoly were (1) price increases (2) quality decrease (3) the tendency to reduce artificers to idleness and beggary. This put a temporary end to complaints about monopoly, until King James I began to grant them again. In 1623 Parliament passed the Statute of Monopolies, which for the most part excluded patent rights from its prohibitions, as well as guilds. From King Charles I, through the civil war and to King Charles II, monopolies continued, especially useful for raising revenue. Then in 1684, in East India Company v. Sandys it was decided that exclusive rights to trade only outside the realm were legitimate, on the grounds that only large and powerful concerns could trade in the conditions prevailing overseas. In 1710 to deal with high coal prices caused by a Newcastle Coal Monopoly the New Law was passed. Its provisions stated that "all and every contract or contracts, Covenants and Agreements, whether the same be in writing or not in writing... are hereby declared to be illegal." When Adam Smith wrote the Wealth of Nations in 1776 he was somewhat cynical of the possibility for change."To expect indeed that freedom of trade should
ever be entirely restored in Great Britain is as absurd as to
expect that
Oceana or Utopia should ever
be established in it. Not only the prejudices of the public, but
what is more unconquerable, the private interests of many
individuals irresistibly oppose it. The Member of Parliament who
supports any proposal for strengthening this Monopoly is seen to
acquire not only the reputation for understanding trade, but great
popularity and influence with an order of men whose members and
wealth render them of great importance."
Restraint of trade
The English law of restraint of trade is the direct predecessor to modern competition law. Its current use is small, given modern and economically oriented statutes in most common law countries. Its approach was based on the two concepts of prohibiting agreements that ran counter to public policy, unless the reasonableness of an agreement could be shown. A restraint of trade is simply some kind of agreed provision that is designed to restrain another's trade. For example, in Nordenfelt v. Maxim, Nordenfelt Gun Co. a Swedish arm inventor promised on sale of his business to an American gun maker that he "would not make guns or ammunition anywhere in the world, and would not compete with Maxim in any way."To be consider whether or not there is a
restraint of trade in the first place, both parties must have
provided valuable consideration for their
agreement. In Dyer's case a dyer had given a bond not to exercise
his trade in the same town as the plaintiff for six months but the
plaintiff had promised nothing in return. On hearing the
plaintiff's attempt to enforce this restraint, Hull J
exclaimed,
"per Dieu, if the plaintiff were here, he should
go to prison until he had paid a fine to the King."
The common law has evolved to reflect changing
business conditions. So in the 1613 case of Rogers v. Parry a court
held that a joiner who promised not to trade from his house for 21
years could have this bond enforced against him since the time and
place was certain. It was also held that a man cannot bind himself
to not use his trade generally by Chief Justice
Coke. This was followed in Broad v. Jolyffe and Mitchell v.
Reynolds where
Lord Macclesfield asked, "What does it signify to a tradesman
in London what another does in Newcastle?" In times of such slow
communications, commerce around the country it seemed axiomatic
that a general restraint served no legitimate purpose for one's
business and ought to be void. But already in 1880 in Roussillon v.
Roussillon Lord Justice
Fry stated that a restraint unlimited in space need not be
void, since the real question was whether it went further than
necessary for the promisee's protection. So in the Nordenfelt case
Lord McNaughton ruled that while one could validly promise to "not
make guns or ammunition anywhere in the world" it was an
unreasonable restraint to "not compete with Maxim in any way." This
approach in England was confirmed by the House of Lords in Mason v.
The Provident Supply and Clothing Co.
Competition law today
Modern competition law begins with the United States legislation of the Sherman Act of 1890 and the Clayton Act of 1914. While other, particularly European, countries also had some form of regulation on monopolies and cartels, the US codification of the common law position on restraint of trade had a widespread effect on subsequent competition law development. Both after World War II and after the fall of the Berlin wall competition law has gone through phases of renewed attention and legislative updates around the world.United States antitrust
The American term anti-trust arose not because the US statutes had anything to do with ordinary trust law, but because the large American corporations used trusts to conceal the nature of their business arrangements. Big trusts became synonymous with big monopolies, the perceived threat to democracy and the free market these trusts represented led to the Sherman and Clayton Acts. These laws, in part, codified past American and English common law of restraints of trade. Senator Hoar, an author of the Sherman Act said in a debate, "We have affirmed the old doctrine of the common law in regard to all inter-state and international commercial transactions and have clothed the United States courts with authority to enforce that doctrine by injunction." Evidence of the common law basis of the Sherman and Clayton acts is found in the Standard Oil case, where Chief Justice White explicitly linked the Sherman Act with the common law and sixteenth century English statutes on engrossing. The Act's wording also reflects common law. The first two sections read as follows,"Section 1. Every contract, combination in the
form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or
commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is
declared to be illegal. Every person who shall make any contract or
engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby declared to be
illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction
thereof, shall be punished by fine....
Section 2. Every person who shall monopolize, or
attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person
or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among
the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty
of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by
fine...."
The Sherman Act did not have the immediate
effects its authors intended, though
Republican President Theodore
Roosevelt's federal government sued 45 companies, and William Taft
used it against 75. The Clayton Act
of 1914 was passed to supplement the Sherman Act. Specific
categories of abusive conduct were listed, including price
discrimination(section 2), exclusive dealings (section 3) and
mergers which substantially lessen competition (section 7). Section
6 exempted trade unions from the law's operation. Both the Sherman
and Clayton acts are now codified under
Title 15 of the United
States Code.
Post war consensus
seealso Competition regulator It was after the First World War that countries began to follow the United States' lead in competition policy. In 1923 Canada introduced the Combines Investigation Act and in 1926 France reinforced its basic competition provisions from the 1810 Code Napoleon. After World War II, the Allies, led by the United States, introduced tight regulation of cartels and monopolies in occupied Germany and Japan. In Germany, despite the existence of laws against unfair competition passed in 1909 (Gesetz gegen den unlauteren Wettbewerb or UWB) it was widely believed that the predominance of large cartels of German industry had made it easier for the Nazis to assume total economic control, simply by bribing or blackmailing the heads of a small number of industrial magnates. Similarly in Japan, where business was organised along family and nepotistic ties, the zaibatsu were easy for the despotic government to manipulate into the war effort. Following, unconditional surrender tighter controls, replicating American policy were introduced.Further developments however were considerably
overshadowed by the move towards nationalisation and
industry wide planning in many countries. Making the economy and
industry democratically accountable through direct government
action became a priority. Coal industry,
railroads,
steel, electricity, water, health care
and many other sectors were targeted for their special qualities of
being natural
monopolies. Commonwealth
countries were slow in enacting statutory competition law
provisions. The United Kingdom introduced the (considerably less
stringent) Restrictive Practices Act in 1956. Australia introduced
its current Trade
Practices Act in 1974. Recently however there has been a wave
of updates, especially in Europe to harmonise legislation with
contemporary competition law thinking.
European Union law
In 1957 six Western European countries signed the Treaty of the European Community (EC Treaty or Treaty of Rome), which over the last fifty years has grown into a European Union of nearly half a billion citizens. The European Community is the name for the economic and social pillar of EU law, under which competition law falls. Healthy competition is seen as an essential element in the creation of a common market free from restraints on trade. The first provision is Article 81 EC, which deals with cartels and restrictive vertical agreements. Prohibited are..."(1) ...all agreements between undertakings,
decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices
which may affect trade between Member States and which have as
their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of
competition within the common market..."
Article 81(1) EC then gives examples of "hard
core" restrictive practices such as price fixing or market sharing
and 81(2) EC confirms that any agreements are automatically void.
However, just like the
Statute of Monopolies 1623, Article 81(3) EC creates
exemptions, if the collusion is for distributional or technological
innovation, gives consumers a "fair share" of the benefit and does
not include unreasonable restraints (or disproportionate, in ECJ
terminology) that risk eliminating competition anywhere. Article 82
EC deals with monopolies, or more precisely firms who have a
dominant market share and abuse that position. Unlike U.S.
Antitrust, EC law has never been used to punish the existence
of dominant firms, but merely imposes a special responsibility to
conduct oneself appropriately. Specific categories of abuse listed
in Article 82 EC include price discrimination and exclusive
dealing, much the same as sections 2 and 3 of the U.S. Clayton Act.
Also under Article 82 EC, the European Council was empowered to
enact a regulation
to control mergers between firms, currently the latest known by the
abbreviation of ECMR "Reg. 139/2004". The general test is whether a
concentration (i.e. merger or acquisition) with a community
dimension (i.e. affects a number of EU member states) might
significantly impede effective competition. Again, the similarity
to the Clayton Act's
substantial lessening of competition. Finally, Articles 86 and 87
EC regulate the state's role in the market. Article 86(2) EC states
clearly that nothing in the rules can be used to obstruct a member
state's right to deliver public services, but that otherwise public
enterprises must play by the same rules on collusion and abuse of
dominance as everyone else. Article 87 EC, similar to Article 81
EC, lays down a general rule that the state may not aid or
subsidise private parties in distortion of free competition, but
then grants exceptions for things like charities, natural disasters
or regional development.
International enforcement
Competition law has already been substantially internationalised along the lines of the US model by nation states themselves, however the involvement of international organisations has been growing. Increasingly active at all international conferences are the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), which is prone to making neo-liberal recommendations about the total application of competition law for public and private industries. Chapter 5 of the post war Havana Charter contained an Antitrust code but this was never incorporated into the WTO's forerunner, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1947. Office of Fair Trading Director and Professor Richard Whish wrote sceptically that it "seems unlikely at the current stage of its development that the WTO will metamorphose into a global competition authority." Despite that, at the ongoing Doha round of trade talks for the World Trade Organisation, discussion includes the prospect of competition law enforcement moving up to a global level. While it is incapable of enforcement itself, the newly established International Competition Network (ICN) is a way for national authorities to coordinate their own enforcement activities.Competition law theory
Classical perspective
seealso Classical economics The classical perspective on competition was that certain agreements and business practice could be an unreasonable restraint on the individual liberty of tradespeople to carry on their livelihoods. Restraints were judged as permissible or not by courts as new cases appeared and in the light of changing business circumstances. Hence the courts found specific categories of agreement, specific clauses, to fall foul of their doctrine on economic fairness, and they did not contrive an overarching conception of market power. Earlier theorists like Adam Smith rejected any monopoly power on this basis."A monopoly granted either to an individual or to
a trading company has the same effect as a secret in trade or
manufactures. The monopolists, by keeping the market constantly
under-stocked, by never fully supplying the effectual demand, sell
their commodities much above the natural price, and raise their
emoluments, whether they consist in wages or profit, greatly above
their natural rate."
In The
Wealth of Nations (1776) Adam Smith
also pointed out the cartel problem, but did not advocate legal
measures to combat them.
"People of the same trade seldom meet together,
even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a
conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise
prices. It is impossible indeed to prevent such meetings, by any
law which either could be executed, or would be consistent with
liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder people of the
same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to do
nothing to facilitate such assemblies; much less to render them
necessary."
Smith also rejected the very existence of, not
just dominant and abusive corporations, but corporations at all.
By the latter half of the nineteenth century it
had become clear that large firms had become a fact of the market
economy. John
Stuart Mill's approach was laid down in his treatise On Liberty
(1859).
"Again, trade is a social act. Whoever undertakes
to sell any description of goods to the public, does what affects
the interest of other persons, and of society in general; and thus
his conduct, in principle, comes within the jurisdiction of
society... both the cheapness and the good quality of commodities
are most effectually provided for by leaving the producers and
sellers perfectly free, under the sole check of equal freedom to
the buyers for supplying themselves elsewhere. This is the
so-called doctrine of Free Trade, which rests on grounds different
from, though equally solid with, the principle of individual
liberty asserted in this Essay. Restrictions on trade, or on
production for purposes of trade, are indeed restraints; and all
restraint, qua restraint, is an evil..."
Neo-classical synthesis
After Mill, there was a shift in economic theory, which emphasised a more precise and theoretical model of competition. A simple neo-classical model of free markets holds that production and distribution of goods and services in competitive free markets maximizes social welfare. This model assumes that new firms can freely enter markets and compete with existing firms, or to use legal language, there are no barriers to entry. By this term economists mean something very specific, that competitive free markets deliver allocative, productive and dynamic efficiency. Allocative efficiency is also known as Pareto efficiency after the Italian economist Vilfredo Pareto and means that resources in an economy over the long run will go precisely to those who are willing and able to pay for them. Because rational producers will keep producing and selling, and buyers will keep buying up to the last marginal unit of possible output - or alternatively rational producers will be reduce their output to the margin at which buyers will buy the same amount as produced - there is no waste, the greatest number wants of the greatest number of people become satisfied and utility is perfected because resources can no longer be reallocated to make anyone better off without making someone else worse off; society has achieved allocative efficiency. Productive efficiency simply means that society is making as much as it can. Free markets are meant to reward those who work hard, and therefore those who will put society's resources towards the frontier of its possible production. Dynamic efficiency refers to the idea that business which constantly competes must research, create and innovate to keep its share of consumers. This traces to Austrian-American political scientist Joseph Schumpeter's notion that a "perennial gale of creative destruction" is ever sweeping through capitalist economies, driving enterprise at the market's mercy.Contrasting with the allocatively, productively
and dynamically efficient market model are monopolies, oligopolies,
and cartels. When only one or a few firms exist in the market, and
there is no credible threat of the entry of competing firms, prices
raise above the competitive level, to either a monopolistic or
oligopolistic equilibrium price. Production is also decreased,
further decreasing social
welfare by creating a deadweight
loss. Sources of this market power are said to include the
existence of externalities, barriers
to entry of the market, and the free
rider problem. Markets may fail to be
efficient for a variety of reasons, so the exception of competition
law's intervention to the rule of laissez
faire is justified. Orthodox economists fully acknowledge that
perfect
competition is seldom observed in the real world, and so aim
for what is called "workable
competition". This follows the theory that if one cannot
achieve the ideal, then go for the second best option by using the
law to tame market operation where it can.
Chicago School
A group of economists and lawyers, who are largely associated with the University of Chicago, advocate an approach to competition law guided by the proposition that some actions that were originally considered to be anticompetitive could actually promote competition. The US Supreme Court has used the Chicago School approach in several recent cases . One view of the Chicago School approach to antitrust is found in United States Circuit Court of Appeals Judge Richard Posner's books' 'Antitrust law and Economic Analysis of LawRobert Bork
was highly critical of court decisions on United States antitrust
law in a series of law review articles and his book The
Antitrust Paradox. Bork argued that both the original intention
of antitrust laws and economic efficiency was the pursuit only'' of
consumer welfare, the protection of competition rather than
competitors. Furthermore, only a few acts should be prohibited,
namely cartels that fix prices and divide markets, mergers that
create monopolies, and dominant firms pricing predatorily, while
allowing such practices as vertical agreements and price
discrimination on the grounds that it did not harm consumers.
Running through the different critiques of US antitrust policy is
the common theme that government interference in the operation of
free markets does more harm than good. "The only cure for bad
theory", writes Bork, "is better theory". The late Harvard
Law School Professor Philip Areeda, who favours more aggressive
antitrust policy, in at least one Supreme Court case challenged
Robert Bork's preference for non intervention.
Policy developments
Anti-cartel enforcement is a key focus of competition law enforcement policy. In the US the Antitrust Criminal Penalty Enhancement and Reform Act 2004 raised the maximum imprisonment term for price fixing from three to ten years, and the maximum fine from $10 to $100 million. In 2007 British Airways and Korean Air pleaded guilty to fixing cargo and passenger flight prices.These actions complement the private enforcement
which has always been an important feature of
United States antitrust law. The
United States Supreme Court summarised why Congress
allows punitive damages in Hawaii v. Standard Oil.
"Every violation of the antitrust laws is a blow
to the free-enterprise system envisaged by Congress. This system
depends on strong competition for its health and vigor, and strong
competition depends, in turn, on compliance with antitrust
legislation. In enacting these laws, Congress had many means at its
disposal to penalize violators. It could have, for example,
required violators to compensate federal, state, and local
governments for the estimated damage to their respective economies
caused by the violations. But, this remedy was not selected.
Instead, Congress chose to permit all persons to sue to recover
three times their actual damages every time they were injured in
their business or property by an antitrust violation."
In the EU, the Modernisation
Regulation 1/2003 means that the European
Commission is no longer the only body capable of public
enforcement of
European Community competition law. This was done in order to
facilitate quicker resolution of competition-related inquiries. In
2005 the Commission issued a Green Paper
on Damages actions for the breach of the EC antitrust rules, which
suggested ways of making private damages claims against cartels
easier.
Competition law practice
Collusion and cartels
The core of competition policy has, since the 1980s, been the anti-price fixing cartel agenda, despite criticism by economic libertarians. In The Wealth of Nations (1776) Adam Smith pointed out the cartel problem, but did not advocate legal measures to combat them. Nowadays a far stricter approach is taken. Under EC law cartels are banned by Article 81 EC, whereas under US law the Sherman Act prohibitions of section 1. To compare, the target of competition law under the Sherman Act 1890 is every "contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy", which essentially targets anybody who has some dealing or contact with someone else. In the mean time, Art. 81 EC makes clear who the targets of competition law are in two stages with the term agreement "undertaking". This is used to describe almost anyone "engaged in an economic activity", but excludes both employees, who are by their "very nature the opposite of the independent exercise of an economic or commercial activity", and public services based on "solidarity" for a "social purpose". Undertakings must then have formed an agreement, developed a "concerted practice", or, within an association, taken a decision. Like US antitrust, this just means all the same thing; any kind of dealing or contact, or a "meeting of the minds" between parties. Covered therefore is a whole range from a strong handshaken written or verbal agreement to a supplier sending invoices with directions not to export to its retailer who gives "tacit acquiescence" to the conduct.Less of a consensus exists in the field of
vertical
agreements. These are agreements not between firms at the same
level of production, but firms at different levels in the supply
chain, for instance a supermarket and a bread producer.
Recently, the United States Supreme Court has become more skeptical
of antitrust cases predicated on agreements between companies that
are not directly in competition with one another, such as a
clothing manufacturer and a clothing retailer, while maintaining
the strict prohibition against agreements that limit competition
between companies at the same level of the supply chain, such as
agreements between two retailers or between two distributors.
Vertical agreements may still be illegal, but the burden of proving
them illegal was raised by a number of recent cases from the
per
se illegal standard to a more demanding rule of
reason standard.
Dominance and monopoly
When firms hold large market shares, consumers risk paying higher prices and getting lower quality products than compared to competitive markets. However, the existence of a very high market share does not always mean consumers are paying excessive prices since the threat of new entrants to the market can restrain a high-market-share firm's price increases. Competition law does not make merely having a monopoly illegal, but rather abusing the power that a monopoly may confer, for instance through exclusionary practices.First it is necessary to determine whether a firm
is dominant, or whether it behaves "to an appreciable extent
independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its
consumer." Under EU law, very large market shares raise a
presumption that a firm is dominant, which may be rebuttable. If a
firm has a dominant position, then there is "a special
responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair competition on
the common market". Similarly as with collusive conduct, market
shares are determined with reference to the particular market in
which the firm and product in question is sold. Then although the
lists are seldom closed, certain categories of abusive conduct are
usually prohibited under the country's legislation. For instance,
limiting production at a shipping port by refusing to raise
expenditure and update technology could be abusive. Tying one
product into the sale of another can be considered abuse too, being
restrictive of consumer choice and depriving competitors of
outlets. This was the alleged case in Microsoft v. Commission
leading to an eventual fine of €497 million for including its
Windows
Media Player with the Microsoft
Windows platform. A refusal to supply a facility which is
essential for all businesses attempting to compete to use can
constitute an abuse. One example was in a case involving a medical
company named Commercial Solvents. When it set up its own rival in
the tuberculosis
drugs market, Commercial Solvents were forced to continue supplying
a company named Zoja with the raw materials for the drug. Zoja was
the only market competitor, so without the court forcing supply,
all competition would have been eliminated.
Forms of abuse relating directly to pricing
include price exploitation. It is difficult to prove at what point
a dominant firm's prices become "exploitative" and this category of
abuse is rarely found. In one case however, a French funeral
service was found to have demanded exploitative prices, and this
was justified on the basis that prices of funeral services outside
the region could be compared. A more tricky issue is predatory
pricing. This is the practice of dropping prices of a product
so much that in order one's smaller competitors cannot cover their
costs and fall out of business. The Chicago
School (economics) considers predatory pricing to be unlikely.
However in France Telecom SA v. Commission a broadband internet
company was forced to pay €10.35 million for dropping its prices
below its own production costs. It had "no interest in applying
such prices except that of eliminating competitors" and was being
crossed subsidised to capture the lion's share of a booming market.
One last category of pricing abuse is price
discrimination. An example of this could be offering rebates to
industrial customers who export your company's sugar, but not to
Irish customers who are selling their goods in the same market as
you are in.
Mergers and acquisitions
A merger or acquisition involves, from a
competition law perspective, the concentration of economic power in
the hands of fewer than before. This usually means that one firm
buys out the shares of
another. The reasons for oversight of economic concentrations by
the state are the same as the reasons to restrict firms who abuse a
position of dominance, only that regulation of mergers and
acquisitions attempts to deal with the problem before it arises, ex
ante prevention of creating dominant firms. In the United States
merger regulation began under the Clayton Act, and in the European
Union, under the Merger Regulation 139/2004 (known as the "ECMR").
Competition law requires that firms proposing to merge gain
authorisation from the relevant government authority, or simply go
ahead but face the prospect of demerger should the
concentration later be found to lessen competition. The theory
behind mergers is that transaction costs can be reduced compared to
operating on an open market through bilateral contracts.
Concentrations can increase economies
of scale and scope. However often firms take advantage of their
increase in market power, their increased market share and
decreased number of competitors, which can have a knock on effect
on the deal that consumers get. Merger control is about predicting
what the market might be like, not knowing and making a judgment.
Hence the central provision under EU law asks whether a
concentration would if it went ahead "significantly impede
effective competition... in particular as a result of the creation
or strengthening off a dominant position..." and the corresponding
provision under US antitrust states similarly,
"No person shall acquire, directly or indirectly,
the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital... of the
assets of one or more persons engaged in commerce or in any
activity affecting commerce, where... the effect of such
acquisition, of such stocks or assets, or of the use of such stock
by the voting or granting of proxies or otherwise, may be
substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a
monopoly.
What amounts to a substantial lessening of, or
significant impediment to competition is usually answered through
empirical study. The market shares of the merging companies can be
assessed and added, although this kind of analysis only gives rise
to presumptions, not conclusions. Something called the Herfindahl-Hirschman
Index is used to calculate the "density" of the market, or what
concentration exists. Aside from the maths, it is important to
consider the product in question and the rate of technical
innovation in the market. A further problem of collective
dominance, or oligopoly through "economic
links" can arise, whereby the new market becomes more conducive to
collusion. It is
relevant how transparent a market is, because a more concentrated
structure could mean firms can coordinate their behaviour more
easily, whether firms can deploy deterrants and whether firms are
safe from a reaction by their competitors and consumers. The entry
of new firms to the market, and any barriers that they might
encounter should be considered. If firms are shown to be creating
an uncompetitive concentration, in the US they can still argue that
they create efficiencies enough to outweigh any detriment, and
similar reference to "technical and economic progress" is mentioned
in Art. 2 of the ECMR. Another defence might be that a firm which
is being taken over is about to fail or go insolvent, and taking it
over leaves a no less competitive state than what would happen
anyway. Mergers vertically in the market are rarely of concern,
although in AOL/Time Warner the European
Commission required that a joint venture with a competitor
Bertelsmann be
ceased beforehand. The EU authorities have also focussed lately on
the effect of conglomerate
mergers, where companies acquire a large portfolio of related
products, though without necessarily dominant shares in any
individual market.
Developing Countries
It is unclear whether competition policy is a
sensible role for government in developing, particularly low-income
countries. In these countries the markets are usually very small
and fragmented so that developing scale sufficient to raise
competitiveness and engage in international markets is a major
challenge. The bigger problem is however poor governance - in
societies with widespread corruption, inadequate public finances,
and weak judiciary and oversight institutions, competition policy
may become another tool for capture by vested interests - becoming
in itself a barrier to entry. The evidence for this is the many
competition authorities around the developing world, that have
achieved little impact.
See also
Notes
References
- Bork, Robert H. (1978) The Antitrust Paradox, New York Free Press ISBN 0465003699
- Bork, Robert H. (1993). The Antitrust Paradox (second edition). New York: Free Press. ISBN 0-02-904456-1.
- Friedman, Milton (1999) The Business Community's Suicidal Impulse
- Galbraith Kenneth (1967) The New Industrial State
- Mill, John Stuart (1859) On Liberty online at the Library of Economics and Liberty
- Posner, Richard (2001) Antitrust Law, 2nd ed., ISBN 9780226675763
- Posner, Richard (2007) Economic Analysis of Law 7th ed., ISBN 9780735563544
- Prosser, Tony (2005) The Limits of Competition Law, ch.1
- Schumpeter, Joseph (1942) The Process of Creative Destruction
- Smith, Adam (1776) An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations online from the Adam Smith Institute
- Wilberforce, Richard, Alan Campbell and Neil Elles (1966) The Law of Restrictive Practices and Monopolies, 2nd edition, London: Sweet and Maxwell
- Whish, Richard (2003) Competition Law, 5th Ed. Lexis Nexis Butterworths
Further reading
- Chalmers, Damien; Hadjiemmanuil, Christos; Monti, Giorgio; Tomkins, Adam (2006) European Union Law, ISBN 9780521527415
- Elhauge, Einer; Geradin, Damien (2007) Global Competition Law and Economics, ISBN 1841134651
- Faull, Jonathan; Nikpay, Ali (eds) (2007) "Faull & Nikpay : The EC Law of Competition"; ISBN-13: 978-0199269297
- Georg Erber and Stefan Kooths, Windows Vista: Securing Itself against Competition?, in: DIW Weekly Report, 2/2007, Vol.3, 7-14.
- Keith N. Hylton et al., Antitrust World Reports, available at http://www.antitrustworldwiki.com
- Competition Policy International (various issues), ISSN 1554-6853, available at http://www.globalcompetitionpolicy.org
External links
antitrust in Bosnian: Antitrust
antitrust in Danish: Antitrust
antitrust in German: Wettbewerbsrecht
antitrust in Modern Greek (1453-): Δίκαιο
ανταγωνισμού
antitrust in Spanish: Derecho de la
competencia
antitrust in French: Droit de la
concurrence
antitrust in Indonesian: Antitrust
antitrust in Italian: Antitrust
antitrust in Malay (macrolanguage):
Undang-undang persaingan
antitrust in Dutch: Mededingingsrecht
antitrust in Japanese: 独占禁止法
antitrust in Norwegian: Antitrust
antitrust in Portuguese: Antitruste
antitrust in Serbo-Croatian: Antitrust
antitrust in Turkish: Rekabet Hukuku
antitrust in Ukrainian: Антимонопольний
комітет
antitrust in Chinese: 反托拉斯法